Rabu, 04 Januari 2012

jurnal internasional MSDM

Human Resource Management: Some Vital Considerations
SK Mishra
Department of Economics
North-Eastern Hill University
Shillong (India) – 793022
I. Introduction: Are human beings ‘resources’? On this question there is a sharp division
in opinions. There are scholars, not much ethically inclined, who adore the practice of
considering human beings as resources. They visualize a continuum – from the inert
objects to the most refined intellectual endeavours – from the one end to the other, as
resources to productive activities. On the other hand, there are a plenty of scholars who
abhor considering human beings just a complement to other means (e.g. animals, plants
and inanimate objects) of production. Tn those scholars it appears debasing to consider
labour - menial or mental, vulgar or artistic, raw or polished - as a commodity and by the
same logic, human beings a source of the flow of labour and its power as resources.
They view workers in the holistic perspective of their psychology and their fitness to their
work environment and work assignment, rather than as interchangeable parts. They place
emphasis on how leadership, cohesion, and loyalty play important roles in organizational
success. They also consider the instinct of workmanship as an important source of value
added to the output they produce
.
II. The Basis of Human Resource Management: Think of the neoclassical schema. In
this schema there are many producers (of a particular commodity or servhce). Each
producer is an employer (of workers in his establishment). He has the means to employ
workers and thereby buy their performance. He is interested in the work performance and
wants to maximize his benefit. On the other hand, there are people who want job (and
possess the required labour power or skill). They too want the best of the deal, possibly
the largest sum in reward nf their work effort. Additionally, as the neoclassical
economics assumes, the producers as well as the workers possess all the information
required for reaching a decision. Also assume that the demanders (the producers) and the
suppliers (workers) of labour are in sufficiently large numbers. The neoclassical schema
suggests that they will reach an agreement on an equilibrium wage. This wage rate would
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1005563
2
be equal to the marginal revenue product (performance) of the worker on the producer’s
side, and to the marginal rate of substitution between income and leisure time on the
worker’s side. In this manner, the interaction between the two forces – the demand and
the supply – determines wages as well as performance. There is hardly anything in this
schema to bring in the need of human resource management (Nienhüser, 2004).
The standard neo-classical schema is extremely idealized, so much so that it has
no resemblance to reality. Although the motives of employers and the (prospective)
employees may not be very far away from the reality, other assumptions of the model are
extremely unrealistic. To assume that the employers have every bit of information
necessary to decision-making is questionable. The same is true with the assumption of
omniscience of the (prospective) employees. Nor is it true that the employers or the
prospective employees have unlimited choice with regard to one another. Furthermore,
once the employer and the employee have reached the agreement, it might not always be
true that each other’s expectations are realized. There are issues related with the moral
hazard, asymmetry (of information, power and institutional support) and a host of other
factors that mediate between expectation, capability and their realization. These issues
call for human resource management.
Let us take up these issues one by one; first, regarding the employer. Who is an
employer? If an establishment is owned as well as managed by a person, who is the sole
decision maker and all profits and losses are due only to him or her, we obtain the one
type of scenario. On the other hand, when an establishment is owned by many persons,
some real and some others as ‘legal persons’ possibly representing the interests of some
organization; some having larger stakes and some others having smaller stakes and so on,
we are faced with an entirely different kind of scenario. This kind of scenario is well
manifest in the joint stock companies. Owners are not the managers. Management is
partly parallel and partly hierarchical. Moreover, the managers are themselves the
employees. A larger part of information available to the one department is not so to the
other departments. In this sort of scenario it is difficult to define the employer. Of course,
for legal purposes the impersonal firm is the employer, but for analytical purposes the
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1005563
3
concept of an employer is only blurred. The concept is blurred furthermore when the
employer is a body politic, like the government.
What are the possible motives of an employer? Is it always true that an employer
wants to maximize profits, as it is almost universally assumed in academic forums?
Profits may apparently have a very definite meaning, but that is only an illusion. A tint of
fuzziness and uncertainty is immediately introduced as soon as we bring in time in our
analysis. A certain decision might be profitable in the short run, but not in the long run or
vice versa. It is not very difficult to find instances of enterprises that take a short run vhew
of profits, care little to build up goodwill or an image of their products in the market and
are chiefly guided by the predatory instinct. By such a strategy, many enterprises in their
short life span have earned huge profits, disappeared forever, but built a fortune, which
they invested elsewhere. On the other hand, many enterprises aspired for profits in the
long run; some of them failed, some others succeeded.
In many cases, however, earning profits is only one of the objectives of an
enterprise. It may have several social objectives. If one takes instances of a few big
entrepreneurs in India, one would find that a few of them have had clearly discernible
social (national) objectives while a few others chiefly aspired for profits. In many other
cases, profits have not been an objective at all. The objective of some enterprises have
been chiefly social and altruistic; their earnings have only met their expenses and
sustained them to remain functional. Or, in some other cases, the objective of an
enterprise may be organic – to survive, grow and wield some power or influence – to
which profits might be only a means.
Then of the assumption that an employer has all of the necessary information
needed to make a decision with regard to employing persons in the establishment. There
are two sides (if not more) of this issue. The first side relates to the requirements in the
establishment. Is an employer sure of those requirements and if yes, in what proportions,
hierarchies, complementarities, priorities and urgencies are those requirements necessary
to meet the objectives of the establishment? Is an employer aware of the possible changes
4
in the structure and composition of those requirements likely to occur in a foreseeable
future? If not, then a correct decision in the current perspective would be utterly out of
place in a future perspective. Since it is not possible to hire or fire employees overnight,
such a decision may ever continue to be a drag on the performance of the organization.
The other side relates to the (prospective) employees. How can we judge the
candidate employees as to their ability, willingness and persistence to fulfill the
requirements of the organization (employer)? This problem is less acute when unskilled
manual labourers are required, especially for casual jobs. But as the requirement of skill
or the span of contract increases, the problem becomes more and more complex. It is a
commonplace that the educational (training) institutions rarely train the pupils to fit into
the requirements of any particular organization. Education, whether in general or
professional institutions, whether in humanities, social sciences, natural or applied
sciences, engineering, medicine, management or the like, continues to be, and can at best
be, only general, inculcating in the pupils the ability just necessary to appreciate the
issues that are relevant to their trades. As Bertrand Russell said once – education is not
imparting knowledge, but inculcating the skill to acquire knowledge.
But how can an employer be sure that the candidate employees are sufficiently
educated or trained? Several methods are used to judge the candidature of the prospective
employees. The foremost is a reliance on the credentials such as the degrees or diplomas
conferred on the candidates by a reputed or professionally recognized educational (or
training) institution. This is often supplemented by personal interviews, written tests, etc.
It is well known that the credentials of a candidate employee, even if issued by the most
reputed educational institutions, are a grossly imperfect measure of his/her ability; much
less of his/her persistent willingness to contribute to the employer organization.
Professionals in particular are very much prone to use the current employer organization
as a jumping pad for an entry to more rewarding organizations. Competitor organizations
themselves tend to promote such endeavours. Thus, employers face uncertainties not only
in recruitment, but also in training and retaining the most promising employees.
5
Let us now turn to the problem of moral hazards. The employer and the employee
reach at an agreement in which each has to give something to the other in exchange of
something. For example, an employee has to perform (do some specified work) in
exchange of a specified amount of salary (reward). In case there is no sensitive and
reliable measure that can assess the performance of the employee or the application of the
measure of performance is costly (time-wise or cost-wise), the employee may not
perform commensurately with the reward he/she gets, and yet, the employer might not be
able to administer his/her performance. This is the instance of the moral hazard. Moral
hazards from employees’ side cannot be reduced without inculcating in them the sense of
loyalty to the organization.
The asymmetry of information, power and institutional support often block the
possibilities of optimal decision-making. Asymmetry in information refers to the fact that
the employer, the manager and the employee each do not or cannot possess information
in equal quantity, quality and variety so as to reach a balance in using those information.
The better informed may gain advantage over the less informed. Asymmetry in power
blocks the advantages to the less powerful in the same way. Further, employees,
managers and the employer do not have equitable support of institutions to protect their
interests. These asymmetries ultimately give rise to conflicts of interests.
III. The Strategy of Dynamic Gradual Optimization: From what has been discussed
above, some vital points emerge. First, although it may not always be possible to identify
a (or a few) person(s) as the employer and the crisply stated objectives which the
organization aspires for, a vague idea of them can always be formed. Further, due to lack
of enough information (or vary high transaction cost of obtaining sufficient information)
the employees recruited by the organization are in most likelihood short of fitness to meet
the objectives of the organization. Thirdly, on account of asymmetries, lack of
appropriate and sensitive measure of performance as well as impracticability of
administration of performance there would be a possibility of moral hazards and
emergence of conflicts of interests among the organization, the management and the
6
employees. All these together would reduce the efficiency of the organization to meet its
objectives.
The purpose of human resource management is to understand the above problems
and gradually work out a series of coherent solutions over time (or identify a path of
evolution) so as to make the objectives of the organization clearer on the one hand, and
nurture the ability, identify the roles as well as direct the spontaneous yet conscious
efforts of employees individually and collectively to best achieve those objectives (of the
organization).
This perspective has several highlights. First, unlike the deterministic, static and
crisply defined (but unrealistic) scenario presented by the academics, it visualizes a
possibilistic, dynamic and vaguely described (fuzzy) scenario, closer to the real world
situation. In this perspective, the goals of an establishment are neither countably
determinate nor clearly defined. The goals evolve over time and gradually make
themselves more vivid. In absence of clearly and arithmomorphically defined goals, the
traditional principles or methods of optimization are not applicable. One has to resort to
satisficing approach to optimization as Herbert Simon (1957, 1962, 1979) pointed out.
Thirdly, identification of a correct solution to the problem is neither necessary nor
feasible. There are multiple paths to reach better and still better solutions and only a
search and gradual betterment strategy is suggested (Firby, 1989).
This perspective also recognizes that organizations are very complex adaptive
systems. A complex adaptive system is a dynamic network of many agents (owners,
managers at different levels, employees of different types at different nodes and the outer
people with whom they interact) acting in parallel, constantly acting and reacting to what
the other agents are doing. The control of such a system tends to be highly dispersed and
decentralized. The overall behavior of the system is the result of a huge number of
decisions made every moment by many individual agents. These systems have a very
high degree of adaptive capacity, giving them resilience to perturbations. They have quite
involved framework of communication, cooperation, specialization and spatio-temporal
7
layout (Waldrop, 1992). Viewed a little differently, their degree of cyclomatic complexity
(refering to the number of nodes of decision, tranfer of control and repetitive loops) is
very high and most often dynamically changing as well as evolving over time. If there is
to be any coherent behavior in the system, it has to arise from competition and
cooperation among the agents themselves.
IV. Some Major Nodes of Decision Making for Human Resource Management:
Human resource management in a typical organization comprises the following processes
that may be considered as the major nodes of decision making and choosing one of the
(many permissible) paths to proceed. These are:
(i) Workforce planning: It is mainly concerned with the visualization of different
activities, processes and their interlinkages in the organization and need for
persons, with requisite skill, to perform those activities. The quality as well as
the number of persons required for various activities is to be determined.
(ii) Recruitment: The next step is to recruit the workforce. It has two major
processes under it. The first relates to ‘attraction’ and the second to
‘selection’. Attraction needs a planned strategy to draw the attention of
qualified persons to the organization. Sometimes this is done by advertisement
but at others the organization has to personally contact the prospective
employees. To strike at the correct strategy to attract right type of persons is
considerably complex. A wrong strategy might be either ineffective or leading
to problems in future. Likewise, the selection of right type of workforce is
very involved. No foolproof method exists to guarantee that the selection
made by any process is best suited to the interests of the organization.
(iii) Induction and Orientation: As it has been noted earlier, no educational
institution can turn out pupils cut and dried to the specific needs of any
particular organization. Education is always ‘general’. Once a person has been
selected to join the workforce of an organization, he/she has to be inducted
and oriented to the specific job. He/she has also to be made aware of the major
objectives of the organization and the environment in which he/she has to
work. It has been observed that at times the managers ‘over-manage’ and in
8
showing loyalty to the organization tend to over-describe. At other times,
managers fail to induct and orient the new recruits to their job, leaving them to
discover their roles by themselves. Over-description as well as underdescription
tends to give a wrong orientation to the new recruits.
(iv) Skills management: It refers to making a matrix of skill or competencies of
different levels required in performing different jobs on the one hand and the
assessment as well as stocktaking of skills of different employees on the other.
Their matching often discloses the gaps between the required and the
available skill, which may suggest additional recruitment or need of training
and development of the (existing) employees. It may be noted that skills
management is an ongoing process in view of the changing internal (within
the organization) as well as external environment.
(v) Training and development: Training and development may be needed first to
bridge the current gap between the required skill for performing a job and that
available with the workforce, and the second in view of the future
requirements of the organization. It is a commonplace that of late the rate of
changes in technology has been very fast. The span of service life of an
employee is always far too larger than the span for which a particular
technology is in mode. As a result, the employees must be trained and
retrained to fit to the technology. Training may be in-house; it may be given
by those organizations that supply new technology or even by a third party. It
may be noted, however, that all employees are not equally amenable to
appreciate the value of training. Nor all of them are equally responsive to
training or interested in learning. The management has to take necessary
measures to induce the employees to be more receptive to learning. The
management also has to look into the quality of training imparted by the
trainers whether individuals or organizations.
(vi) Time management: It refers to identification, listing, sorting and prioritizing
the tasks to be done and allocating time on them. The management should
train its employees to manage their time when at work or at home (since
performance of a person at either place impinges on the performance at the
9
other place). Although an exercise in time management itself may take some
time, but ultimately it increases efficiency. There are many methods of
prioritization of tasks, among which the ABC method, the POSEC (prioritize,
organize, streamline, economize and contribute) method and Eisenhower
method are notable. The Eisenhower method uses importance and urgency as
the two coordinates making four categories of tasks. The less urgent and less
important tasks are the last in priority while the most urgent and most
important tasks are the first to attend. It is advisable to use a ‘secondary
memory’ device (such as written task list or a computer note pad/diary) than
the ‘primary memory’, i.e. keeping the list and the priorities in mind, which is
easy to forget or get confused. As computers are easily available now, one
may use software that have built-in task hierarchy schedulers and support
numerous chores of ordering and listing of tasks with their details. The
management should also keep information on how the employees have
planned the use of their time in performing the tasks and rationalize them
where needed. The culture of time management has to inculcated and
promoted among the employees.
(vii) Travel management: It refers to rationalization of movement of the
employees from their residence to the workplace and their return back home
as well as their movement elsewhere for performing certain sort of tasks
related to the organization. It may encompass residential planning, including
availability of amenities and facilities, for the employees as well. A properly
done travel management may increase the efficiency of employees manifold.
(viii) Management of payroll, compensation in wage/salary and benefits
administration: Various methods may be adopted to pay salary/wages to the
employees that save their time on the one hand and the cost/time of the
organization in disbursement. For example, instead of paying them in cash on
a fixed day every month (which may make long queues and kills the entire
day), payments may be made to employees’ savings accounts. Charges for
certain types of benefits given to the employees may be deducted from their
salaries directly. Employees’ benefits encompass all non-wage or non-salary
10
benefits given to them partly to increase their economic security and partly to
induce them to be more effective and loyal to the organization. These benefits
include perks, housing, conveyance, group insurance, health care, day care,
children’s tuition fee reimbursement, funding of education, various types of
leave, vacation, travel allowances, subsidized lunch during the work hours,
voluntary retirement schemes, retirement benefits, etc. All these benefits
increase the cost on the part of the organization, but if properly planned and
administered, they may also increase the returns from the employees
manifold. On the other hand, a faulty planning and execution of these benefits
may result into employees’ dissatisfaction and a consistent resistance from the
employees’ unions, often leading to loss of workdays and degeneration of the
relationship between the employees and the organization/management.
(ix) Performance appraisal: It refers to the regular assessment and review of the
performance of employees in terms of quantity, quality, cost and time. Its
objectives are to (i) give feedback to employees as to their performance so as
to make them aware of their contribution, (ii) identify employee for training
and skill augmentation, (iii) document criteria used to allocate organizational
rewards, (iv) form a basis for promotions, disciplinary actions, special raises
in personal salaries, etc. (v) provide the opportunity for organizational
diagnosis and development, (vi) facilitate communication between employee
and management, and (vii) validate selection techniques and human resource
policies to meet certain norms. In many cases, the performance appraisal is
done through the ‘upward feedback system’ in which the managers get a
feedback through reports or they review the performance of the employees
diectly. However, the ‘360-degree feedback system’ also is very often used
for performance appraisal. This method relies on the feedback received from
different internal sources such as subordinates, peers and managers, selfassessment
of the employees, as well as external sources such as customers
and suppliers or other stakeholders. The 360-degree feedback system often
works better than the simple upward feedback system. Drucker (1954)
suggested that management by objectives (MBO) is often very successful in
11
understanding of objectives of the organization and enhancing the
performance. Management by objectives is a process in which the
management and the employees discuss and reach at a consensus on the
objectives of the organization, the degree of success in meeting them,
obstacles to meet them and the ways and means to meet them better. We have
mentioned before how and why the objectives of an organization become
clearer to the employees only gradually. The MBO method is only a process
to that end. It itroduces the criteria of specificity, measurability, achievability,
reality and time-specificity in the objectives and therby promotes performance
of employees (inculding management). For a heathy functioning of the
organization it is required to develop the management information system to
help monitor the ‘reach ratio’ ( a ratio of achievement to target).
V. Broadening the Concept of Human Resources: So far, the scope of human resource
management has been limited to the in-house persons employed by the organization. It
also concentrates mainly on production (and distribution to some extent). However, of
late, the scope of human resource management has been widened in view of the
generalized definition of human resources. Now, under human resources one includes all
those people – employees, agents, dealers, distributors, retailers and customers including
consumers in the forward chain and the suppliers of inputs in the backward chain – who
are related to an organization and whose behaviour may have some effect on the
performance of the organization. This change has brought in the concept of ‘crowdsourcing’.
It “can improve productivity and creativity while minimizing labor and
research expenses. Using the Internet to solicit feedback from an active and passionate
community of customers can reduce the amount of time spent collecting data through
formal focus groups or trend research, while also seeding enthusiasm for upcoming
products. By involving a cadre of customers in key marketing, branding, and productdevelopment
processes, managers can reduce both staffing costs and the risks associated
with uncertain marketplace demand.” (Alsever, 2007-b).
12
It is obvious that the broadening of definition of human resources has chiefly been
a result of the revolution in the information and communication technology. As Alsever
(2007-b) points out, with the rise of user-generated media such as blogs, Wikipedia,
MySpace, and YouTube, the traditional distinctions between producers and consumers
have been blurred. Although the idea of soliciting customer input is hardly new, the
advent of open-source software movement has shown that now it can be done with everlarge
number of people. The difference is that today's technology makes it possible to
enlist ever-larger numbers of non-technical people to do ever-more complex and creative
tasks, at significantly reduced cost.
Proctor & Gamble has used crowd-sourcing for research and development of their
Prigles Prints Chips. O'Reilly Media, a publishing company, has done it for sales
reporting. Chipotle Mexican Grill, a restaurant chain, has applied crowd-sourcing for
advertising and Threadless, a youth-oriented fashion manufacturer, has benefited in
product designing and selection by crowd-sourcing. Alsever (2007-c)
It may be noted, nevertheless, that the methods of managing the employees differ
significantly from the methods of managing the non-employees, especially the
customers/consumers. The organization must not expect to control them, but to allow
them to be creative and be themselves. The organization may lay out ground rules about
how much control it is willing to cede, how much information it is willing to share, and
what will happen to the work that the participants create. Alsever (2007-a) points out that
people will do many things (for an organization) just for free, simply because they think
it is fun. Products and companies can become hobbies unto themselves, and many
consumers will derive satisfaction from feeling like an insider at a company they're
passionate about. In return, the concerned organization should give them recognition,
exclusive perks, the opportunity to interact with senior company managers, or free
products.
VI. Concluding Remarks: The nodes of decision-making for human resource
management described above readily suggests us that in real life one cannot make a tight,
static and closed optimization model of human resource management. The network of
13
decision nodes characterizes multiple paths from the one to the other and every path is
uncertain, fuzzy and information-wise imperfect. Decision-making at any node requires a
prohibitively large cost of information, not feasible to be met in real life. Under this
condition, there is no alternative to the strategy of dynamic gradual optimization.
Although it is easy to say that the objectives should be crisp, quantifiable and specific,
but in real life it is not easy to obtain them. One has to deal with fuzziness. Moreover, for
clarity of analysis it is assumed that the objectives or the measures of performance are
independent of each other, but again, in reality, they are often interdependent to some
extent. This situation is analytically inconvenient, but, being real, has to be dealt with. It
may also be noted that while minimization of the degree of asymmetry of information
between the employees and the management might help in better understanding and
improved performance, it depends much on the institutional framework how symmetry
(or asymmetry) in information would be used. Certain institutional systems are conducivd
to efficiency and performance, while certain others have led to a (possibly misplaced)
weight system on equity, justice and performance. The practice of human resource
management cannot override the overall institutional framework completely. As a result,
the satisficing behaviour, although clearly sub-optimal, may be the only resort. It is also
important to go along with the recent development in information technology that has
blurred the distinction between the producers and the consumers. Customers, if allowed
to interact and managed properly, can be a major but very cheap and effective source of
research, development and advertising. Crowd sourcing has a great potential to help meet
the objectives of an organization and it should be included in human resource
management practice.
References
• Alsever, J (2007-a): “How to Get Your Customers to Solve Problems for You”.
http://www.bnet.com/2403-13068_23-52960.html
• Alsever, J (2007-b): “What is Crowdsourcing?” http://www.bnet.com/2403-
13068_23-52961.html
• Alsever, J (2007-c): “The New Human Resource”. http://www.bnet.com/2403-
13240_23-52962.html
14
• Drucker, PF (1954): The Practice of Management. Harper & Row, New York.

• Firby, R (1989): Adaptive Execution in Complex Dynamic Worlds. Ph.D. thesis.
Department of Computer Science. Yale University. New Haven, Connecticut.
• Nienhüser, W (2004): “Political [Personnel] Economy – A Political Economy
Perspective to Explain Different Forms of Human Resource Management
Strategies”. Management Revue, vol. 15 (2), pp. 228-248.
• Simon, HA (1957): Models of Man. Wiley, New York.
• Simon, HA (1962): “The Architecture of Complexity”. Proceedings of the
American Philosophical Society, vol. 26, pp. 467-482.
• Simon, HA (1979): “Rational Decision Making in Business Organizations”.
American Economic Review, vol. 69, pp. 493-513.
• Waldrop, MM (1992): Complexity: The Emerging Science at the Edge of Order
and Chaos. Simon & Schuster, New York.
A Bibliographical Note
The publications of the Human Resource Development Academy at the College of
Technology, Bowling Green State University, Bowling Green, OH 43403-0280, USA at
its website http://www.ahrd.org provide very rich reading and research materials on
human resource development. These resources are freely downloadable. (Note that some
files are quite large and contain research papers in the volumes exceeding 1000 pages).
The Academy of Human Resource Development was formed to encourage systematic
study of human resource development theories, processes, and practices; to disseminate
information about HRD, to encourage the application of HRD research findings, and to
provide opportunities for social interaction among individuals with scholarly and
professional interests in HRD from multiple disciplines and from across the globe.

Nama    : Merlyawati Priyantini
NIM       : 098554053
Kelas     : TN ’09 A (pagi)
Biddy     : MSDM
e-mail: unesa.merly@gmail.com

Tidak ada komentar:

Posting Komentar